Tillbaka till svenska Fidonet
English   Information   Debug  
UFO   0/40
UNIX   0/1316
USA_EURLINK   0/102
USR_MODEMS   0/1
VATICAN   0/2740
VIETNAM_VETS   0/14
VIRUS   0/378
VIRUS_INFO   0/201
VISUAL_BASIC   0/473
WHITEHOUSE   0/5187
WIN2000   0/101
WIN32   0/30
WIN95   0/4281
WIN95_OLD1   0/70272
WINDOWS   0/1517
WWB_SYSOP   0/419
WWB_TECH   0/810
ZCC-PUBLIC   0/1
ZEC   4

 
4DOS   0/134
ABORTION   0/7
ALASKA_CHAT   0/506
ALLFIX_FILE   0/1313
ALLFIX_FILE_OLD1   0/7997
ALT_DOS   0/152
AMATEUR_RADIO   0/1039
AMIGASALE   0/14
AMIGA   0/331
AMIGA_INT   0/1
AMIGA_PROG   0/20
AMIGA_SYSOP   0/26
ANIME   0/15
ARGUS   0/924
ASCII_ART   0/340
ASIAN_LINK   0/651
ASTRONOMY   0/417
AUDIO   0/92
AUTOMOBILE_RACING   0/105
BABYLON5   0/17862
BAG   135
BATPOWER   0/361
BBBS.ENGLISH   0/382
BBSLAW   0/109
BBS_ADS   0/5290
BBS_INTERNET   0/507
BIBLE   0/3563
BINKD   0/1119
BINKLEY   0/215
BLUEWAVE   0/2173
CABLE_MODEMS   0/25
CBM   0/46
CDRECORD   0/66
CDROM   0/20
CLASSIC_COMPUTER   0/378
COMICS   0/15
CONSPRCY   0/899
COOKING   31539
COOKING_OLD1   0/24719
COOKING_OLD2   0/40862
COOKING_OLD3   0/37489
COOKING_OLD4   0/35496
COOKING_OLD5   9370
C_ECHO   0/189
C_PLUSPLUS   0/31
DIRTY_DOZEN   0/201
DOORGAMES   0/2048
DOS_INTERNET   0/196
duplikat   6002
ECHOLIST   0/18295
EC_SUPPORT   0/318
ELECTRONICS   0/359
ELEKTRONIK.GER   1534
ENET.LINGUISTIC   0/13
ENET.POLITICS   0/4
ENET.SOFT   0/11701
ENET.SYSOP   33864
ENET.TALKS   0/32
ENGLISH_TUTOR   0/2000
EVOLUTION   0/1335
FDECHO   0/217
FDN_ANNOUNCE   0/7068
FIDONEWS   23936
FIDONEWS_OLD1   0/49742
FIDONEWS_OLD2   0/35949
FIDONEWS_OLD3   0/30874
FIDONEWS_OLD4   0/37224
FIDO_SYSOP   12852
FIDO_UTIL   0/180
FILEFIND   0/209
FILEGATE   0/212
FILM   0/18
FNEWS_PUBLISH   4336
FN_SYSOP   41622
FN_SYSOP_OLD1   71952
FTP_FIDO   0/2
FTSC_PUBLIC   0/13595
FUNNY   0/4886
GENEALOGY.EUR   0/71
GET_INFO   105
GOLDED   0/408
HAM   0/16059
HOLYSMOKE   0/6791
HOT_SITES   0/1
HTMLEDIT   0/71
HUB203   466
HUB_100   264
HUB_400   39
HUMOR   0/29
IC   0/2851
INTERNET   0/424
INTERUSER   0/3
IP_CONNECT   719
JAMNNTPD   0/233
JAMTLAND   0/47
KATTY_KORNER   0/41
LAN   0/16
LINUX-USER   0/19
LINUXHELP   0/1155
LINUX   0/22068
LINUX_BBS   0/957
mail   18.68
mail_fore_ok   249
MENSA   0/341
MODERATOR   0/102
MONTE   0/992
MOSCOW_OKLAHOMA   0/1245
MUFFIN   0/783
MUSIC   0/321
N203_STAT   918
N203_SYSCHAT   313
NET203   321
NET204   69
NET_DEV   0/10
NORD.ADMIN   0/101
NORD.CHAT   0/2572
NORD.FIDONET   189
NORD.HARDWARE   0/28
NORD.KULTUR   0/114
NORD.PROG   0/32
NORD.SOFTWARE   0/88
NORD.TEKNIK   0/58
NORD   0/453
OCCULT_CHAT   0/93
OS2BBS   0/787
OS2DOSBBS   0/580
OS2HW   0/42
OS2INET   0/37
OS2LAN   0/134
OS2PROG   0/36
OS2REXX   0/113
OS2USER-L   207
OS2   0/4786
OSDEBATE   0/18996
PASCAL   0/490
PERL   0/457
PHP   0/45
POINTS   0/405
POLITICS   0/29554
POL_INC   0/14731
PSION   103
R20_ADMIN   1121
R20_AMATORRADIO   0/2
R20_BEST_OF_FIDONET   13
R20_CHAT   0/893
R20_DEPP   0/3
R20_DEV   399
R20_ECHO2   1379
R20_ECHOPRES   0/35
R20_ESTAT   0/719
R20_FIDONETPROG...
...RAM.MYPOINT
  0/2
R20_FIDONETPROGRAM   0/22
R20_FIDONET   0/248
R20_FILEFIND   0/24
R20_FILEFOUND   0/22
R20_HIFI   0/3
R20_INFO2   3138
R20_INTERNET   0/12940
R20_INTRESSE   0/60
R20_INTR_KOM   0/99
R20_KANDIDAT.CHAT   42
R20_KANDIDAT   28
R20_KOM_DEV   112
R20_KONTROLL   0/13205
R20_KORSET   0/18
R20_LOKALTRAFIK   0/24
R20_MODERATOR   0/1852
R20_NC   76
R20_NET200   245
R20_NETWORK.OTH...
...ERNETS
  0/13
R20_OPERATIVSYS...
...TEM.LINUX
  0/44
R20_PROGRAMVAROR   0/1
R20_REC2NEC   534
R20_SFOSM   0/340
R20_SF   0/108
R20_SPRAK.ENGLISH   0/1
R20_SQUISH   107
R20_TEST   2
R20_WORST_OF_FIDONET   12
RAR   0/9
RA_MULTI   106
RA_UTIL   0/162
REGCON.EUR   0/2056
REGCON   0/13
SCIENCE   0/1206
SF   0/239
SHAREWARE_SUPPORT   0/5146
SHAREWRE   0/14
SIMPSONS   0/169
STATS_OLD1   0/2539.065
STATS_OLD2   0/2530
STATS_OLD3   0/2395.095
STATS_OLD4   0/1692.25
SURVIVOR   0/495
SYSOPS_CORNER   0/3
SYSOP   0/84
TAGLINES   0/112
TEAMOS2   0/4530
TECH   0/2617
TEST.444   0/105
TRAPDOOR   0/19
TREK   0/755
TUB   0/290
Möte WHITEHOUSE, 5187 texter
 lista första sista föregående nästa
Text 3983, 976 rader
Skriven 2007-01-22 23:31:14 av Whitehouse Press (1:3634/12.0)
Ärende: Press Release (0701227) for Mon, 2007 Jan 22
====================================================

===========================================================================
Press Briefing on the President's State of the Union Health Care Initiative
===========================================================================

For Immediate Release
Office of the Press Secretary
January 22, 2007

Press Briefing on the President's State of the Union Health Care Initiative
White House Conference Center


˙˙˙˙˙ In Focus: Health Care ˙˙˙˙˙ State of the Union 2007

PARTICIPANTS
Julie Goon, Special Assistant to the President for Economic Policy
Katherine Baicker, Council of Economic Advisors

3:59 P.M. EST

MR. FRATTO: Good afternoon. Thanks for coming on relatively short notice.
We wanted to give you all an opportunity to dig in a little bit to the
health proposals that President Bush alluded to in his radio address this
weekend, and make sure that you have an opportunity to talk to some of our
policy experts and to get a little bit deeper into it so that we're all on
the same page.

We're excited about the proposals the President put forth and will put
forth tomorrow night in his State of the Union address. We've asked Julie
Goon, who is with the National Economic Council and a health care policy
expert, and Kate Baicker is a member of the Council of Economic Advisors,
to give a fuller briefing on both -- we're going to talk about both
proposals. I'm going to ask Julie to come up first to frame up the issue in
the context of President Bush's -- the way he views health care and health
care reform. And then we'll ask Kate to get in a little bit more deeply on
the tax proposal and how that will affect health care and health care
reform.

So, Julie, do you want to come up and lead us off?

MS. GOON: Thanks, Tony, and thanks to all of you who are here today.

I think I just want to start out by saying the President has had a whole
series of health policies that continue to remain the foundation of the
things that we are doing in the health care area, including the work that
is going on with respect to transparency and getting more information
available to consumers; the work with respect to health information
technology and health savings accounts, trying to make insurance more
portable across state lines, et cetera.

But in looking at the coming year and recognizing that this is the year
that the state Children's Health Insurance Program is up for
reauthorization, that this is a good year to really refocus and re-target
on a lot of the ideas that people have had about how to provide for more
insurance coverage for people who don't have access to that coverage right
now.

The President felt that it was important that we ensure that affordable
coverage is available in the states, that is why an important piece of what
he's going to be talking about tomorrow has to do with the Affordable
Choices Initiative that will help states who make basic private affordable
health insurance available in their states, provide additional help to
those states to help subsidize insurance coverage for people who are poor
and who are uninsurable at this point.

And I think Secretary Leavitt has been very instrumental in pulling this
initiative together. He's been talking to a lot of governors who have come
forward with their own ideas. We'll be doing more of that over the next
several weeks, and the President will be talking about that, as well, in
the State of the Union. And it's part of the fact sheet on health care that
came out today.

Complementary to that is the need to address some of the biases in the tax
system and reform the tax code to realign those incentives to provide for
more of a reason for people to purchase health insurance coverage. As many
of you know, right now you have a tax benefit for the purchase of health
insurance coverage if you purchase it within the employment setting. If you
have to buy health insurance in the non-group setting you do not get that
same kind of tax advantage.

And so the tax reform proposal that the President will put forward in the
State of the Union levels the playing field between insurance coverage
purchased inside the employer market and outside the employer market, and
does it in a fairly innovative and creative way, in a way I think that we
haven't seen before, and Kate will be able to talk in more specific detail
about that. But, essentially, it puts in place a standard uniform deduction
for the purchase of health insurance coverage. So if you purchase coverage,
you get this deduction, and it's the same for everybody.

This is an immediate benefit to people who don't have insurance now who
have wanted to purchase it but haven't been able to do so because of the
cost of health insurance coverage and because they don't get this tax
benefit. It's an immediate benefit to people who have purchased coverage in
the non-group market already, and it helps a majority -- millions of
Americans who currently have insurance coverage through their employer --
will get additional tax benefit as a result of this change in policy.

There have been a lot of people who have been concerned that doing
something like this doesn't necessarily improve the market for health
insurance, and I would just like to point to our experience over the last
couple of years in the Medicare Part D program. As many of you remember,
when that debate started, folks didn't think there would be people who
would be interested in offering prescription drug coverage in the Medicare
program. A number of companies came forward to do so. Initially the
actuaries estimated that the cost of that coverage would be fairly high,
and would grow. And as all of you know, when seniors and other
beneficiaries got a look at the choices that were available to them, what
was in those benefit packages and what the costs were, as a result of their
choices, we have a very competitive market in Medicare Part D, and the
average premium is down 40 percent from what it was anticipated to be when
that program first started.

So getting back to the specifics on the tax piece, why don't I turn it over
to Kate, and then we're both available to answer more questions on this.
Thank you.

MS. BAICKER: Thanks. So Julie did a great job laying out the big landscape
of what we'd like to do, and then I'm going to be the geek and try to
explain how it actually works. So any clarifying questions would be most
welcome.

As you know, right now when you get insurance through your employer, that
insurance isn't subject to taxation, so it's part of your compensation that
you're getting income and payroll tax-free. And that means that people have
a really strong incentive to get more generous employer policies to cover
all the health care they might want to consume because if you go out into
the health care marketplace to buy a doctor's office visit, you're usually
paying for that with after-tax dollars. But if you get that covered by your
employer-provided plan, it's covered with pre-tax dollars, and that's a big
discount. And that's a lot of the reason why we see such generous
first-dollar coverage in the employer market as the norm, unlike other
industries, like auto insurance or home owner's insurance.

So what this proposal would do is change the system to level the playing
field in two ways. It will level the playing field for people who are
buying insurance on their own, relative to those who are getting it in the
employer market, or through their jobs. And it will level the playing field
for people who want to get basic policies with lower premiums, and then pay
for routine care out of pocket relative to people who want to get more
generous, deluxe, gold-plated plans. Right now the most generous tax
benefits are reserved for people with the most generous employer-provided
health insurance.

What this plan would do is give a flat, standard deduction for anybody who
purchases any kind of health insurance, no matter how much the health
insurance costs and no matter where they get it. It would be $15,000 for
people purchasing family policy, $7,500 for people purchasing single
policies. So if your employer is giving you insurance through your job, you
get the standard deduction. If you go buy health insurance on your own, you
get the standard deduction. If your policy costs $5,000, you still get
$15,000 of compensation tax-free. If your policy costs $20,000, you still
get $15,000 of compensation tax-free, using the family example.

So who does this help, who does this hurt, what's the total cost? It's
revenue-neutral over the whole health care system and over the 10-year
budget window. Anybody who doesn't have insurance right now has a really
strong incentive to go get insurance. Right now an insurance policy on the
individual market or the non-group market, if you're just going to get your
own family policy, the average cost of one of those policies right now is
about $5,200.

Take a family earning $60,000 in the 15-percent income tax bracket,
15-percent payroll tax bracket, if they are currently uninsured and they go
buy insurance, under the current system it costs them $5,200 today. Under
this system in 2009, once it phases in, they get $15,000 of compensation
tax-free. They're paying 30 percent marginal tax rate on that, so that's
$4,500. That's a huge chunk of the cost of an insurance policy out there.
So it makes insurance much more affordable for those people.

So anybody who is uninsured right now is a big winner under the proposal.
So are people who are buying insurance on their own. If you're out there
and you've already purchased your own non-group insurance or your own
insurance not through your job, for the most part you're getting no tax
benefit. So this is a pure win for you. Your tax bill goes down.

Now, what about people getting insurance through their jobs right now?
Anybody getting a policy under the standard deduction, a family policy of
less than $15,000, or an individual policy of less than $7,500 would
immediately see a lower tax bill. That's because they would get a standard
$15,000 deduction for a family, but then they would have to count as
taxable income their insurance policy, but it would be lower than the
$15,000, so their tax bill would go down.

That's 80 percent of the policies offered in the employer market. So as of
January 1, 2009, when this policy gets implemented, we hope, if you look at
all the policies offered in the employer market, 80 percent of them would
be under that standard deduction. So those policies would be subject to
lower taxes.

Twenty percent of the policies, the ones that are left, are actually higher
than the standard deduction. And that means that if people didn't change
their behavior at all, their tax bills would go up because they would be
taxed on the extra amount above the standard deduction. So if your policy
for your family costs $20,000, you get the standard $15,000 deduction --
that leaves $5,000 extra taxable income that you'd have to pay income and
payroll taxes on that you don't now. So those 20 percent of people might
see their tax bills go up. On the other hand, they have some time between
now and then to change their compensation packages.

One of the things that we think is inefficient about the way our tax system
treats health care is the strong subsidy for more generous
employer-provided policies relative to everybody else -- people buying
insurance on their own or people getting less-generous policies. This would
give people a chance as they're negotiating contracts with their employers
to take more of their compensation in the form of wages and less in the
form of health benefits. So that 20 percent has some recourse between now
and then.

The other way that helps keep the whole package revenue neutral is that the
$15,000 or $7,500 would be indexed to CPI, not general health care costs,
and one of the goals of this policy is really to rationalize our health
care spending so that we're getting higher-value, more efficient care, and
we hope in the long run that that substantially brings down the trajectory
of growth in national health spending overall, because people will be
purchasing higher-value plans, they'll be allocating their health care
dollars more efficiently. We think that will bring down national health
spending both immediately, as people change the quantity of health
insurance versus wages that they take in their compensation packages, and
even more in the long run, as there's an incentive to develop a more
rational, efficient health care system, more cost-effective technology,
more provider competition.

So that's the bare bones, but I bet that there are questions.

Q When you talk about the cost of your insurance policy being $15,000 or
$7,500, are you just counting the employer side or is it the employee and
employer side?

MS. BAICKER: So the deduction, the standard deduction has nothing to do
with how much your health insurance costs under this proposal. That's the
part that's hard to get your mind around because it's so different from how
it works right now.

So if you -- no matter how much your health insurance costs, no matter how
much is spent on your health insurance by you and your employer, you get a
$15,000 deduction for your family. Now is that a win or a loss for you? It
depends on how much you were spending before, and really it depends on how
much you were spending with pre-tax dollars before. Now, for everybody the
employer portion is pre-tax. For most people in big firms, the employee
contribution is pre-tax, too, because you're doing it through a cafeteria
plan or an FFA. For some people, their employee share towards their
employer premium was already being taxed.

So when we think about the tax benefit that you get because of the standard
deduction, that doesn't depend at all on how much your health insurance
policy costs. But when you think about how much that is relative to what
you're paying now, you want to think about how much of your premium now is
getting paid with pre-tax dollars. For most people, that's the employer
plus the employee share. For some people, it's just the employer share.

Q If I want to know if I'm over the threshold and I'm going to be taxed, I
add what I'm throwing in, plus what my employer is throwing in?

MS. BAICKER: So let me put it another way, your taxable income, if this
policy is implemented, will be your wages and anything your employer is
paying for health insurance. You're already paying your share out of your
wages, so your total taxable income is the check that you get, plus
whatever your employer has paid directly to the health insurance company.
You may have to give back some of your check for the health insurance. And
then you get to take off of that $15,000. And so for 80 percent of policies
that $15,000 is more than what was getting pitched in. But for some people,
it might be less.

Q The figure I saw was that in '05, most employer-provided health policies
were running $11,000-plus.

MS. BAICKER: I believe today in '07, the average employer policy is $11,500
--

MS. GOON: For a family.

MS. BAICKER: For a family, or I think the average family policy overall, so
it incorporates the mix of the number of people in the family. Then the
policy gets implemented -- this proposal will be implemented in 2009 -- the
$11,500 average today, if you were to inflate that up to 2009 so that you
could compare it to the $15,000 would be more like $13,600. And that's the
number that we used to figure out the 80 percent-20 percent breakdown.

Q But you're saying -- since we're dealing here with marginal tax rates
based on a $15,000 deduction.

MS. BAICKER: All the calculations were done in 2009 dollars.

Q The assumption then is that a family of four is going to be able to find
a $5,000 health plan and not the $13,600 --

MS. BAICKER: No, there's no assumption like that -- no, no, no.

Q I'm sorry, I misunderstood then. I thought you said that --

MS. BAICKER: I gave some examples, and I hope that those weren't taken as
the general rule, so let me --

Q A $15,000 tax deduction, assuming a 30-percent tax bracket, gives you
$4,500 to pay for your health plan.

MS. BAICKER: Exactly. Right, and so then I gave as a benchmark for you a
comparison for what the average individual market policy costs. But that
doesn't mean everybody would find it for that. I was just trying to give
you a sense of how far that would go for a family that's on their own. So
one of the groups that we're concerned about, the uninsured; we're
concerned about families who are going out on their own to buy health
insurance; and then we're concerned about people getting insurance from
their employer, and I tried to give you some statistics for each group.

Q Let me ask one other question if I can. It seems like there are some
people at the bottom end of the scale who make too much to qualify for
Medicaid and not enough to benefit from the tax deduction. How large a
group is that?

MS. BAICKER: That's why the two proposals that Julie talked about dovetail
so nicely, and I'll turn back to her in a second. But I'll remind you that
it's income and payroll taxes. So some of the -- think about families who
are earning too little to pay income taxes, too much or with the wrong
family structure to be on a public program. They're still getting the
payroll tax benefit, which is substantial.

Q Social Security and Medicare?

MS. BAICKER: Right, and that's 15 percent, so they're still getting 15
percent of $15,000 or 15 percent of $7,500 for an individual, even if they
have no income tax liability. That said, there are going to be some groups
for whom that's not enough to get them a health insurance policy because
somebody is sick, because they're very low income. And for those groups,
the Affordable Choices Initiative is there to help fill in the gaps.

MS. GOON: And as Kate said, that's why these two policies are so
complementary. A lot of states have been looking at their options to try
and use the flexibility that was given to them in the Deficit Reduction
Act, to do waivers in their Medicaid programs, to look at subsidizing
coverage beyond the Medicaid eligibility groups, et cetera. And the
Affordable Choices Initiative is a way that we want to help states who want
to make insurance affordable for their citizens by ensuring that we are
providing additional federal help towards that end as long as the state is
committed to making basic affordable health insurance available in that
state.

Q I have a question on the phase-in period. What do you have in mind? I
presume the deductions would be lower in the earlier year?

MS. BAICKER: The deductions would start at $15,000 for a family, $7,500 for
an individual in '09, when it took effect, and then they would be indexed
to CPI, so they would grow gradually over time.

Q So you're assuming it starts in 2009, I'm sorry, I misunderstood. And
also --

MR. FRATTO: That's the phase in. There's no, sort of --

MS. BAICKER: There is nothing until 2009, and then it's here.

Q And then the other question, is this perhaps an indirect way of trying to
encourage more health savings accounts, since it seems like a lot of
people's encouragement here is to buy high-deductible standard policies,
which often can be paired with HSAs?

MS. BAICKER: Certainly HSAs are a great step in this direction, and this is
an even bigger step towards leveling the playing field and removing some of
the weird disincentives to getting basic insurance and paying for routine
care out of pocket. What this really does is give people the flexibility to
structure plans that work best for them.

So you can think about -- you could get a lower premium by having a higher
deductible, by having a smaller panel of physicians covered, by having more
cost sharing throughout the distribution of spending, by all sorts of
different ways. And those policies would be on equal footing if you got
them in the group market or the non-group market. So it really frees up a
lot of parameters for people. That said, HSAs are a great thing and remain
in the tax code.

Q One other question. For those that are uninsured now, it's arguable that
some of them, because they don't have insurance, or have preexisting
conditions that might be rejected, or they might have to pay quite a bit
more for a standard policy, and how does your plan address --

MS. GOON: Well, this gets back, again, to the Affordable Choices Initiative
with the states, and working with the states to encourage better funding of
uninsurable risk pools, which many states have, some states don't; but
working with the states to really identify how best to target additional
subsidies to people who need insurance in that state. In many cases, it
will be people who have preexisting conditions, in other cases it will be
more of the poor.

Q How will this affect retirees who have supplemental coverage, A, and when
does it become revenue-neutral? Is it revenue neutral immediately, or does
that come with the indexing?

MS. BAICKER: So question one, it treats all people with private health
insurance the same way. So it doesn't matter where you're getting it -- if
you're buying it on your own, if it's through a former employer or a
current employer, as long as you have at least catastrophic coverage or
better, then you get the standard deduction. So retirees are given the same
benefits from the tax code as everybody else. So it really levels the
playing field for them.

As for revenue-neutral, it's revenue-neutral over the 10-year window
together. So in the early years, it's a revenue loser, and in the later
years, it's a revenue winner.

Q When does it become a revenue winner?

MS. BAICKER: I don't have that in front of me. Roughly in the middle. But
I'll check. But there's a -- I think it's roughly in the middle, but I'll
have to check that for you.

Q Do you know what it's going to cost the first year?

MS. BAICKER: Again, I don't have that whole stream in front of me. We can
get that information for you. And that will be in the budget.

Q Is this in any way part of a long-term philosophy to wean people off of
employer-provided plans that have become so burdensome for employers?

MS. BAICKER: This is part of a long-run philosophy to level the playing
field, and to really let people pick the mix of compensation that's best
for them. People like getting their insurance through their employer, and
they're going to continue getting their insurance through their employer
for a lot of people. Some people may go to the non-group market once this
playing field is more level for them, and they have that option. And a lot
of people who are not getting any insurance are going to have options open
to them that weren't open before. But it's definitely part of a long-run
philosophy to level the playing field and let people change their
compensation mix accordingly.

Q Does this administration believe that employer-provided care has become
overly burdensome for business?

MR. FRATTO: That's a decision for -- that's not a question for us. What
this reform does is remove inequities in the tax code, where you have a
certain part of America that receives a 100 percent benefit, and another
portion of our citizens that receives zero or near zero benefit through the
tax code. We think about it as tax reform that levels the playing field and
provides a basic, standard benefit to all Americans.

How it affects businesses -- there are dynamics there that will work out
between businesses and their employees. I could tell you businessmen who --
business owners who are in the administration, people who -- people like
Secretary Paulson and Al Hubbard and others who have run businesses feel
that their employees want employer-provided health coverage and they want
to provide it because it's their way of attracting the best talent. And so
there are incentives here that we can't predict -- that's going to be
decided between businesses and their employees.

MS. BAICKER: And just one thing to add on. The health care system overall,
because of the inefficiencies that are built in, is a big burden on all of
us. It's a big burden on employees and employers and taxpayers and the
federal budget. And something needs to be done to rein in health care
spending because we're not getting value for our dollars. So this proposal
will be a big step in the direction of getting more bang for the buck for
our health care spending, because I think nobody in the country can afford
to keep spending more and more and more money on a health care system
that's broken.

Q This will be a tax hike for some people?

MS. BAICKER: This is revenue-neutral tax reform. There are always going to
be some winners and some losers, but the people who might initially be
losers have options.

Q Maybe this follows on her question, maybe I didn't quite get the answer.
Can you explain, how does this affect Medicare recipients, and also people
with Medicare but who buy supplemental policies? I just didn't quite grasp
the --

MS. GOON: If you buy supplemental policies right now, I don't think you get
any tax benefit from that, because you're doing it all in after-tax
dollars.

MS. BAICKER: This is for purchasers of private health insurance.

Q So, in other words, let's say you're a retiree, but you also have, like
-- you're buying AARP insurance --

MS. GOON: So I'm retiree on Medicare?

Q A retiree on Medicare, but you're also buying AARP. Do you get the
deduction, or not?

MS. GOON: I think we have to get back to you on that, but I don't think
this speaks to this supplemental insurance. It's traditional --

Q Primary health insurance?

MS. GOON: Yes, primary health insurance. And Medicare is taking care of
that for those beneficiaries.

Q I wonder -- I'm just doing some quick back-of-the-napkin math here -- at
what point does the average cost of a family plan cross over that $15,000
barrier and the deduction there no longer is as effective as if it were
under the -- two or three years --

MS. BAICKER: At $15,000.

Q Yes, but how long does that take? Two or three years --

MS. BAICKER: Oh, the average policy get to $15,000? A few years after 2009.
I can sort of do a back of the envelope, that if it goes from $11,500 to
$13,600 between now and 2009, then I'm going to say --

MS. GOON: I think we'd want to get back to you on that.

MS. BAICKER: Yes.

MR. FRATTO: Just to be clear, any projections on that are relatively static
projections, right?

MS. GOON: Right.

MS. BAICKER: Absolutely.

MS. GOON: They don't take into account changes in the health care
marketplace that we expect to occur as a result of this policy.

Q Do you think they'll ever cross that?

MS. GOON: I didn't say that.

Q How large do you expect that impact to be on the health care marketplace,
though?

MS. BAICKER: There are a number of channels through which this will affect
health care consumption. Immediately it will affect quantities that people
consume because they'll be changing their mix of compensation and their
choice of health care plan. It will affect prices through provider
competition. And then in the long run, it will affect the development of
more cost-effective health technology. And that's your real bang for the
buck.

Putting all of that together, our best guess is that within the
medium-term, you're talking about lowering health expenditures, a share of
GDP, by about half a percentage point, and that's a lot of money.

MR. FRATTO: And if there's any question as to whether the health care
delivery system, in terms of selling health policies, acts in any way like
a market today, ask yourselves right now -- and I won't ask for a show of
hands -- but if anyone here knows what the value of your policy is, what
you pay for health care. I'd say very few of you have any -- and I don't
know, either. Very few of us have any idea of what our health policies
cost.

So that's compensation that we're receiving from our employees that we have
zero transparency on. It doesn't show up in your W2 form; you have no idea
of what that share of your compensation is.

And I'll ask a second question -- is when was the last time you were
sitting at home eating dinner with your family and received an annoying
phone call from a health insurer trying to market you a health care plan?
This just doesn't happen today because there isn't the market for it.
Insurance companies are not out there trying to sell you the best policy at
the best price.

Q But they are trying to sell employers? Clearly --

MR. FRATTO: That's right.

Q -- it's an aggressive market.

Q Do you want us to get annoying phone calls? (Laughter.)

MR. FRATTO: Exactly. (Laughter.)

Q I get them from you all the time, Terry. (Laughter.)

Q What is the cost of this over five years?

MS. BAICKER: I don't have the year-by-year breakdown. So it's
revenue-neutral over the 10-year window and it's a loser in the first five
years, and a winner in the second five years -- or at the beginning and at
the end, but I don't know exactly where the break-even point is.

Q What about for the next budget? I mean, what is the number that's going
to show up there?

MS. BAICKER: It does not affect the 2012 budget -- deficit. So that maybe
the tipping point --

Q -- deficit, is the question.

MS. BAICKER: I think it's a revenue loser in the short run, and a revenue
winner in the long run.

Q What is the figure that's going to --

MS. BAICKER: I'll have to get that for you. I don't have that number in my
head.

Q You're saying that this is going to be a boon or help 80 percent of the
people -- how much? What are your calculations about what that means in
terms of money coming back to people?

MS. BAICKER: I have -- well, I can tell you a couple of numbers which are
not exactly the number you want, unfortunately, but they're close. The
family who is purchasing insurance on their own, how much are they going to
get back on average? They're going to get back $3,650 on average, roughly.
So that's not the -- so their tax bill is going to go down by $3,650
because of this policy. Because they're buying health insurance on their
own right now and they're not getting any tax benefit. So that's one group.

Another group, people who are uninsured right now, but that we guess would
-- we project would go get insurance because of the policy, they're going
to get a tax benefit of around $3,350.

The last one that you wanted to know is what's the average benefit for that
80 percent of employers, and I don't have that one. So I'll get that one.

MR. FRATTO: Do you want to talk about the share in the quintiles --

MS. BAICKER: Yes. So here's another -- here's a statistic that also speaks
to that indirectly. If you look at the distribution across the income
distribution -- so how much of a tax benefit does the lowest quintile get
versus the highest quintile because of the policy? About -- the top
quintile, the top 20 percent of income has a slight tax increase because of
this. The other four quintiles, first, second, third, fourth, have a tax
decrease.

So it's budget neutral overall, but it makes the tax code slightly more
progressive than it was before, so it's a slight increase for people at the
high end of the income distribution, and a slight tax decrease for
everybody else.

Q What is the average tax increase then?

MS. BAICKER: I do not have the average tax increase handy, but the percent
increase for the top quintile is .1 percent, a tenth of a percent. And then
the -- for the top quintile. And then for the other quintiles, it looks
like it averages around negative .3 percent. But we'll get you the dollar
figure.

Q If we have 47 million uninsured Americans now, at the end of your
five-year window, if it starts in '09, what's the uninsured number then?

MS. BAICKER: So there are two pieces of this policy. From the tax proposal
we think upwards of 3 million or more newly insured people. But then that's
one piece. Then there is the Affordable Choices Initiative.

MS. GOON: Yes, and I don't think that they've got complete estimates on the
number of uninsured. They think that will pick up. It depends on, again,
how these negotiations go with the states and what they expect to do. But
initial estimates were fairly significant, and we'll get that to you.

Q Can you help me clarify the competition -- is the idea that people will
move out of their employer-offered plans --

MS. BAICKER: The idea is that right now people face a dulled incentive to
figure out what the highest value of care is, because the tax system
subsidizes only care that you get through an employer insurance plan and
not care that you purchase out-of-pocket. So it pushes you into a
first-dollar insurance coverage plan where you pay for even routine care
with a really low co-pay, which means you don't ask the doctor how much it
costs. It costs you $10.

I know -- has anyone ever tried to ask the doctor, how much does this visit
cost? They can't even tell you, they don't know. So this would add forces
of competition and people evaluating which providers are the highest value
providers, which insurance plan is the highest value plan for me, because
it's no longer subsidized relative to wages. And that also works really
well with the President's information executive order, getting better
information about prices, about quality, about different providers,
cost-effectiveness. You need that information to help people make better
decisions and to get higher value out of the system.

MR. FRATTO: Let me -- because this question came up a couple times -- let's
just be very clear on that point also. The shortest answer is, no. Are you
asking, is there a bias in the administration towards trying to get people
off of employer-provided health care? Flat-out no. In no way. What we have
are people receiving employer-provided benefits that are subsidized through
the tax code, and those on the other side of the room here who are
receiving no benefits. And the effort is to try to provide a standard
equitable share of the benefit.

Q But would it be fair to say there is a bias toward encouraging employees
to buy a high deductible, lower premium policy?

MS. BAICKER: There's a bias now against that, that we're trying to remove.
We're trying to level the playing field.

MS. GOON: And as Kate had indicated, there may be lower cost plans that
rely on other techniques -- smaller panels of doctors, more utilization
review. It provides a bias towards people looking at the cost of their
coverage and trying to determine if what they've got is really what they
need for their situation.

Q Can you say how much revenue this raises from the 20 percent who would --

MS. BAICKER: That, again, I don't have with me except to say that it's
revenue-neutral. So that is exactly equal to the revenue given out to
everybody else once you have the indexing. I don't have that handy.

MR. FRATTO: You're asking for a year-by-year breakdown. And we'll work with
our friends at Treasury. I know that they're going to do some work on this
also, and we'll see at some point over the next couple days if we can have
it. But as Julie mentioned, this will show up in the budget.

Q Is there a tax impact, then, on employers?

MS. BAICKER: No, so that's a good clarifying question. There's some
confusion over that, so let me try to explain it as best I can. And then
you can ask again and then I can try again. Right now employers don't pay
taxes on the wages that they pay their employees, or the health insurance
benefits. Those are all cost of business. They're not taxed. That remains
the same. So nothing changes there.

What changes is that the health insurance premiums that they pay on your
behalf becomes taxable income to you just like any other form of wages, so
it's treated just like --

Q There's a tax break basically. There's a tax break for the employer, and
you're doing a tax break for the individual. So it's a double tax break.

MS. GOON: The tax break for the employer remains the same.

MS. BAICKER: So as far as the employer is concerned, everything is the same
except they now treat this premium that they were paying for you just like
they treat the wages that they paid you. So it shows up on your W2. It's
FICA -- payroll taxes are due on it and income taxes are due on it. But you
get to take the first $15,000 of your compensation -- if you have a family
plan -- tax-free. So for 80 percent of the policies offered by employers,
that's going to be -- that $15,000 is going to be more generous than the
add-on of the premium that you're getting paid.

Q Do you have a projection for the average savings from someone buying
insurance on their own? Did you mention a projection for the person whose
employer is now providing insurance?

MS. BAICKER: That was the question that was asked that I could not answer,
so I'm going to get a number for you, and have to get back to you.

Q Can I just clarify -- you're saying 3 million out of the 47 million will
be benefited under this tax change?

MS. BAICKER: That will be the net increase in the number of insured people
just from the tax piece alone, then layered on top of the affordable
choices initiative.

Q And why is that uninsured number so intractable in response to changes in
the tax code?

MS. BAICKER: Some of the people are not earning any money, some of the
people are sick, some of the people are choosing not to take up insurance.
So because it's a very heterogeneous group of people who are uninsured,
it's hard to find one magic bullet. It takes a system of policies to
address their diverse needs, and they have different needs in different
states. And that's part of the reason to rely on state initiatives to
address the specific needs of that uninsured group. So this picks up a lot
of people, but you really need some targeted programs.

Q Can you explain again how this becomes revenue-neutral? What happens in
that five years?

MR. FRATTO: Ten years.

MS. BAICKER: The main thing that changes is that the $15,000 or $7,500
initial exclusion is indexed by inflation, not by projected health costs.
So if people did not change their behavior at all, the exclusion would be
going up like this, and premiums would be going up like this. And so more
people would be finding their premiums higher than the $15,000 over time if
they didn't change their behavior.

So that's -- the baseline, when you decide whether something is
revenue-neutral or not, you're comparing it to the status quo. And in the
status quo, health care costs are rising, rising, rising, whereas in this
system the exclusion grows at a lower rate, grows at CPI -- inflation --
and we think people will change their behavior, although that -- to the
extent they change their behavior it just looks even better than that. But
because the $15,000 exclusion grows more slowly than health expenses would
if we didn't do anything, in the beginning you spend a little bit more
money and in the end you get a little bit more money back.

MR. FRATTO: There's also a market impact here that we think will have an
affect on the future pricing of health care policies, and that's the fact
that the benefit is where it is; that you have a benefit that is -- you
have a $7,500 standard deduction for individuals, $15,000 for families.
There is an incentive for those marketing health insurance to get within
that number and to trend towards CPI, because that's what -- the people
they're marketing it to, whether they're getting it through their employers
or buying it on their own, will want to have the full benefit. And so
they're going to try to market plans that fit within the benefit.

MS. GOON: And again, you can look at the Part D experience, and that's
exactly what happened in the second year of bids in Part D, is that people
who were at the high end of those policies brought down their premiums.

Q That just makes the whole program more expensive, right? I mean, it's the
20 percent who are over 15 come under whatever the standard is, and it can
get more expensive.

MS. BAICKER: Because your tax benefit is flat, and so your tax benefit is
the $15,000 exclusion for the families, $7,500 for individuals. We don't
expect that people are taking compensation cuts because of this; they're
changing their mix of compensation between wages and health insurance. But
under this system, wages and health insurance are both taxable. So people
may -- we expect that health spending will go down, because people will
say, wait a minute, now that you're not subsidizing my health insurance
relative to my other wages, I'd like my next raise to come in the form of
cash, not in the form of more expensive health benefits. But both of those
would be taxable under this system.

So that mix of compensation will no longer affect tax revenues and will no
longer affect an individuals' well being, and that's the great thing about
it, is that people will no longer distort their compensation towards health
insurance, because we're pushing them towards it. We won't be doing that
anymore.

Q I'm wondering, if the idea is to have insurers target their plans to the
$7,500 and $15,000, isn't the other incentive there for them to increase
co-pays or to lower the benefits they're providing in order to meet that
mark, just as much as it is to improve the efficiency and delivery?

MS. BAICKER: So this is a good question, because it highlights again the
incentive properties of this proposal. Now there's an incentive for
insurers to put together more generous packages, because we're subsidizing
health insurance relative to everything else. Once we stop subsidizing
health insurance relative to anything else, there's no need to -- there's
no reason they'd anchor on the $15,000 or the $7,500, they would put
together plans that were cheaper and cheaper and cheaper until people found
a plan that they really liked.

So there's no tax reason to stick at $15,000 any more than there is at
$10,000 or $5,000. It's all the same. There's no marginal subsidy of health
insurance relative to anything else, there's just a strong incentive to get
any health insurance package, but then there's no incentive to pick one
over the other. So what we expect is for insurers to put together packages
that best suit the needs of the people enrolling in them.

So for you, you might like a really high deductible, and then no co-pays.
And you might like 10-percent cost sharing up to $20,000. And you might
like first-dollar coverage for everything because you hate writing the
checks. You all have different preferences and needs, and the insurers
wouldn't be pushed in one direction or the other. So we'd expect to see
insurers competing on value of the package, and they have a lot of tools
that they can access to put together a package that's highest value for
you.

MR. FRATTO: At the best price.

MS. BAICKER: At the best price.

Q I had a couple questions. So the President is going to acknowledge that
he would be raising the taxes on 20 percent of the public, do you know how
many people that is?

MS. BAICKER: That's not quite right.

Q Okay, okay. And then the second question is, wouldn't this be encouraging
people to get -- both the people, the 20 percent to get less quality health
care than they're getting now so that they're not paying extra taxes? And
overall, wouldn't that be true on everybody because everybody would be
saying, well, if I get the very least health care I possibly can get, then
I can get more cash in terms of my taxes, therefore, and aren't you sort of
doing a race to the bottom in terms of how much coverage people would be
getting?

MS. BAICKER: So let me first correct a small factual thing and then answer
the bigger question overall. So the 20 percent is -- let me put the 20
percent in context again. Twenty percent of employer policies offered now
are above that standard deduction. So it's not 20 percent of people,
everybody in the whole country. It's 20 percent of employer policies, so --

Q Do you know how many people that is?

MS. BAICKER: That is about, ballpark, 30 million.

Q So 30 million people in this country, their taxes would go up?

MS. BAICKER: If they didn't change their behavior. But people will have
time to think about what mix of compensation they want. And this goes to
your second question about race to the bottom, which is right now, we've
rigged it so there's a race to the top. We've said we're subsidizing you
more if you get a more generous employer-provided insurance relative to
anything else you could consume. So people have been pushed in that
direction.

When you remove that push, people are going to pick what they like best. If
you ask people, would you like the absolute cheapest health insurance
policy you can find? I bet most people will say, no, I want a high value
policy that gives me the mix of financial protection that I want, and I'm
going to trade off what my family wants to do with that money: Do I want to
put it towards health insurance? Do I want to put it towards other family
priorities? And you expect insurers to compete to give people the best plan
at the lowest price for what those people want. And I don't think people
want the minimum insurance. I think people want good insurance at a
reasonable price, and right now we're just pushing them up towards
first-dollar coverage plans. And when you remove that push, they're going
to choose what works out best for them.

MS. GOON: And there's an assumption, too, that the most generous policy is
the highest quality. And I don't think that that's ever been borne out.

Q But you are saying -- I mean, with the $7,500, with the $15,000, if a
person says, oh, geez, I'd rather get the tax break, and I'll gamble on
having the lowest possible health insurance I can get, they do that, and
that way they're getting more money back from --

MS. BAICKER: But, see, the amount of money they get back is a flat amount.
It's the $15,000 standard deduction for a family no matter how much their
health insurance costs, that's the tax benefit that they get. So then they
decide how much do I want to spend on health insurance based on all the
things I could spend my money on.

MR. FRATTO: And just to be clear, there's a significant part of the
population today that are gambling on buying no health insurance or being
under-insured today because they can't afford it, and they certainly can't
afford it relative to those who receive the benefit through their
employers. And this gives them an added incentive to be appropriately
insured, or insured at all, which today they're not.

Q So just quickly, if we could talk just a little about the other part of
this plan, the President wants to redirect funds away from institutions, I
guess, towards states to help people get insurance. How much money is going
to be set aside for that component? And how many people do you think will
be insured ultimately at a result of that effort?

MS. GOON: Well, I think that more of those details will be available in the
budget when it comes out. But it's dependent on how the states react. A lot
of states have come forward already with proposals that would do similar
things to what is being proposed in the Affordable Choices Initiative. It
is to be hoped that most states will look at this as an opportunity to
really take on the federal help that would come to help reform their
insurance marketplace in their state and help subsidize coverage for the
people that are currently uninsured in their states.

Q You don't have, like, an order of magnitude? I mean, a ballpark figure,
what you think the government will be --

MS. BAICKER: I don't have it with me, no. And I think, as I said, you'll
see more of that in the budget when the budget comes out. And I could --

MR. FRATTO: We have to leave something for after the President actually
announces this, Sheryl.

Q -- and the numbers of people that you would expect would be insured? Will
it be more than the 3 million?

MS. GOON: I don't know the answer to that, and we'd have to get back to
you.

Q Because if it's not, it, frankly, doesn't -- it doesn't seem like you're
really making that much of a dent in the problem. It's sort of an admission
that this problem of the uninsured is intractable, can't really be solved.

MR. FRATTO: I think we are being -- I want to use caution to say this, but
I think we're being conservative in our estimates going forward on this. I
think we want to be very careful on our estimates. And we certainly don't
want to oversell, because a lot of us believe that it will have a greater
impact than what -- than the numbers that we've shown you.

MS. BAICKER: That's exactly right.

Q Is the 3 million, and that this other component will be greater than
that?

MR. FRATTO: Greater than the 3 million that Kate mentioned?

MS. GOON: Yes, again, I don't know what the numbers are. But I think these
two policies working together we think are going to have a substantial
impact on getting people insured that currently do not have insurance
coverage.

MR. FRATTO: John.

Q Within this proposal, you are subsidizing health care purchased outside
the employer-based system, and, to some degree, taxing care provided or
insurance provided within that system. Is it right to look at this as a
step on the road away from the employer-based system, and would that be a
good thing, given the strain that's under, especially given the competitive
pressures on American companies?

MS. BAICKER: So, keep in mind that we're leveling the playing field between
the employer market and the individual non-group market. So it's not that
we're taxing one to pay for the other. People should get the same tax
benefit, no matter where they get their insurance.

That said, we've seen over the past many years a slow erosion of employer
offering, and it's reall